// Read more here: // https://my.onetrust.com/s/article/UUID-d81787f6-685c-2262-36c3-5f1f3369e2a7?language=en_US //
You are using an outdated browser.
Please upgrade your browser
and improve your visit to our site.
Skip Navigation

The Birth of American Finance

The Founders and Finance: How Hamilton, Gallatin, and Other Immigrants Forged a New Economy
By Thomas K. McCraw
(Harvard University Press, 485 pp., $35)

THOMAS K. MCCRAW believed that financial leadership in government really matters. Since this is an issue that is very much with us at the present, his work of history may have a special timeliness. In The Founders and Finance, McCraw (who died in November) contends that the secretaries of the Treasury during the several decades following the inauguration of the new national government of the United States in 1789, especially Alexander Hamilton and Albert Gallatin, were crucially responsible for putting the nation’s finances on a sound institutional footing. Indeed, he argues, their actions as government officials made possible the extraordinary explosion of entrepreneurial and capitalist energy in early nineteenth-century America.

It didn’t happen right away. In fact, McCraw notes, “the United States government started out on a shoestring and almost immediately went bankrupt.” To fight its War of Independence from Britain, the government borrowed from banks in Holland and extracted loan after loan from France, impoverishing its ally in the process. The Continental Congress, which was the only federal authority in the decade following the Declaration of Independence, lacked taxing power and consequently had to rely on requisitions from the thirteen states for funds; but it received only a fraction of what it needed. In place of taxes the Congress simply printed scads of paper money that drastically lost its value. “The War of Independence,” McCraw writes, “not only impoverished the country, but also left it burdened with the highest public debt it has ever experienced, measured against the income of its government.”

Burdened by this huge debt and other financial problems, the new country in the 1780s could easily have broken apart. In order to highlight the achievement of the Founders in creating the Constitution of 1787, McCraw tends to exaggerate the economic trouble of the 1780s. He even claims that the decade of “the 1780s was likely the worst decade in American history except for the 1930s.” In making such an exaggerated claim he has to set aside the work of such historians as Merrill Jensen, E. James Ferguson, and others. There certainly was economic dislocation in the 1780s, and traditional markets were closed to American merchants—but new ones were being found, even as far away as China, and people were on the move.

The decade was actually a time of great release and expansion, and the general mood among ordinary people was high and far from bleak. “There is not upon the face of the earth a body of people more happy or rising into consequence with more rapid stride, than the inhabitants of the United States of America,” Charles Thomson, secretary of the Confederation Congress, told Jefferson in 1786. “Population is encreasing, new houses building, new lands clearing, new settlements forming, and new manufacture establishing with a rapidity beyond conception.” Indeed, as the demographer Jim Potter has pointed out, the 1780s were the fastest-growing decade demographically in all of American history. Since immigration was negligible in the 1780s (many Loyalists left the country), the extraordinary growth of population came from young people having high expectations for the future and consequently marrying earlier, which in turn led to their having more children.

MCCRAW ignores all this and remains content with the traditional Federalist view, made most famous by John Fiske’s The Critical Period of American History in 1888, according to which the country’s desperate situation under the Articles of Confederation was rescued in the eleventh hour by a few high-minded Founders. McCraw’s interpretation is not all that different from Fiske’s. The United States was “blessed,” he says, “with a handful of people who understood finance and also grasped the economic potential of the American national future.”

What impresses McCraw most about this handful of people who saved the country is the fact that “a disproportionate number of them were recent arrivals from almost a dozen different places overseas.” Their experience as immigrants—their boldness and their rootlessness—gave them, in his account, a peculiar knowledge of money matters and the nature of capital and credit, and they brought this facility to bear on the economic policies of the United States government. This special knowledge made them ideal candidates for secretary of the Treasury: “During the first fifty years under the Constitution, only six of the sixty persons appointed to the presidential cabinets had been born abroad. Five of the six became secretaries of the treasury.”

Both Robert Morris, the superintendent of finance under the Confederation, and Alexander Hamilton, the first secretary of the Treasury, had migrated to the continental colonies as teenagers, Morris from Liverpool and Hamilton from the Caribbean. President Jefferson and then President Madison appointed Albert Gallatin, born in Geneva, as secretary of the Treasury. When Gallatin left office to negotiate the end of the war with Britain that had begun in 1812, Madison appointed in succession two more immigrants as secretary of the Treasury: George W. Campbell, who had come from Scotland in 1772, and Alexander James Dallas, who had migrated from Jamaica in 1783. “Thus,” concludes McCraw, “four of the first six secretaries of the treasury were born overseas. They served for twenty-one of the first twenty-seven years under the Constitution—78 percent of that period.”

McCraw backs up his point with some interesting statistics. “Of the next sixty-seven secretaries, serving into the twenty-first century, only two were born abroad, and their combined service lasted less than two years out of almost two hundred.” The earlier dominance of foreign-born in the Treasury was not because they constituted a greater proportion of the U.S. population during the period from 1789 to 1816 than in later periods. Indeed, “in 1816 the proportion of foreign-born was probably no more than about 4 percent, among the lowest in U.S. history.”

It is not clear how much we should make of the fact that most of the early secretaries of the Treasury were immigrants. Hamilton was born in 1755 in Nevis, a British colony, which made him just as much a British subject as someone born, say, in the colony of Georgia in the same year. But Hamilton was called a foreigner by those who hated him. John Adams, for example, called him “the bastard Brat of a Scots pedlar” who was “as much a foreigner as Gallatin.” Yet to label Hamilton a foreigner because he was born outside what later became the United States is to assume anachronistically the existence of the nation before the fact. Hamilton did eventually come to believe that he was a stranger in the United States, lamenting in 1802 that “every day proves to me more and more that this American world was not made for me”; but his alienation was based not on his birthplace but on his confrontation with the “real Disease” afflicting America, which, he said on the eve of his fatal duel, was “DEMOCRACY.”

What seems to set the early secretaries of the Treasury apart from other American leaders is not just their status as immigrants, but also their previous mercantile experience and their familiarity with numbers. Hamilton and Gallatin had one or another of these advantages. So did Oliver Wolcott, Hamilton’s replacement at Treasury. Although Wolcott was not foreign-born—he came from an old Connecticut family—he nevertheless was an able secretary of the Treasury.

BUT THIS THEME of foreign-born Treasury secretaries, interesting as it may be, does not dominate the book. Once McCraw completes his introduction he drops the theme, and slips into a more or less conventional political narrative of the life of Hamilton followed by the life of Gallatin. Much of his clearly written narrative about these two men’s lives goes well beyond financial matters. He devotes an entire chapter to Hamilton’s fatal duel with Aaron Burr.

Hamilton, who served as secretary of the Treasury in Washington’s administration from 1789 to 1795, was certainly well-prepared to handle the new government’s financial problems. He had run a merchant house in the Caribbean as a teenager, and he was incredibly smart—smarter than any of the Founders. He could read a paragraph and extract its meaning faster than anyone, and he could write a meaningful paragraph faster than anyone as well. As McCraw points out, many of Hamilton’s legal colleagues thought he was “the best trial lawyer of his generation.”

Hamilton read books on public finance, and he learned about what Great Britain was doing in the eighteenth century in overhauling its system of public finance. He came to understand banks as few of his fellow Americans ever did. America in 1789 had nothing like the array of different monetary notes and the dozens of private and county banks that existed in Britain. Unlike Britain, America was still an overwhelmingly rural and agricultural society. Consequently, banking, in the words of the Philadelphia merchant Thomas Willing, “was a pathless wilderness, ground but little known to this side of the Atlantic.” Even someone as learned and widely read as Jefferson had no understanding of banks, and he consequently hated them. Their issuing of paper money, he remarked, was designed only “to enrich swindlers at the expense of the honest and industrious part of the nation.” John Adams had no better grasp of the secret of banking and the banks’ issuing of paper money: he believed that “every dollar of a bank bill that is issued beyond the quantity of gold and silver in the vaults, represents nothing, and is therefore a cheat upon somebody.”

Hamilton’s great achievement was establishing a financial system in emulation of Britain’s. That Britain, a tiny island off the northwest coast of Europe with a third of the population of France, had come to dominate the world as no nation had since the fall of Rome was the marvel of the age. This eighteenth-century “fiscal-military state,” in John Brewer’s apt term, could mobilize money and wage war as no state in history ever had. Unlike France, Britain’s centralized administration had developed an extraordinary ability to extract money from its subjects without impoverishing them. The secret of the Hanoverian monarchy’s success, as Hamilton had come to appreciate, was its system of centralized tax collection and its funded national debt together with its banking structure capped by the Bank of England and its market in public securities. This system made possible the financing of Britain’s successful eighteenth-century war machine.

Hamilton aimed to copy this British system. He proposed gathering together all the Revolutionary War debts of the Confederation and states and funding them, that is, transforming them into a more or less permanent debt on which annual interest would be paid. At the same time he proposed the creation of a national bank that would stabilize the credit of the United States and create money. He also projected the eventual development of manufacturing in the United States, not just to meet military requirements but also to create a more diversified economy that would be more self-reliant and less dependent on European supplies. Undergirding this financial program was Hamilton’s plan for a modern, hierarchically governed state with a bureaucracy, a standing army, and a strong navy. With Britain as his model, Hamilton thought that the United States would eventually, perhaps in four or five decades, become itself a strong “fiscal-military state” capable of taking on any of the European states on their own terms.

But McCraw doubts that this fiscal-military state could have been Hamilton’s goal. “The idea and the reality of a ‘fiscal-military state,’” he says, “simply do not fit the political economy of the early Republic.” McCraw ignores the fact that Hamilton’s vision of a fiscal-military state was a long-term one, not something immediately attainable. It did indeed take a long time, much longer than Hamilton imagined. Only after experiencing the Jeffersonian state-centered society with a small national government of the antebellum period that culminated in a civil war did the United States begin to realize Hamilton’s dream, which took four or five decades following the nationalizing results of the Civil War.

In 1790, Hamilton and his fellow Federalists could not foresee that long period of Jeffersonian minimal government and the development of egalitarian democracy. Hamilton was no fool. He knew very well that the American people were not yet ready for the kind of government that he envisioned. He told Washington in 1789 that “notions of equality” were as “yet ... too general and too strong” for the kind of high-toned society and government that he assumed would eventually develop in America. Hard as it is for us to understand, Hamilton and the Federalists actually thought that time was on their side, that—in accord with the theories of the stages of social development popular in the late eighteenth century—the society of the United States would sooner or later become mature, less egalitarian and more hierarchical, and even more monarchical. Of course, he and the other Federalists could not have been more wrong. This was only one of the many illusions that the Founders had about the future.

SINCE MCCRAW seems unable to take seriously Hamilton’s vision of a fiscal-military state in emulation of that of Britain, he has no adequate way of explaining James Madison’s otherwise strange and sudden opposition to Hamilton’s program. Hamilton was certainly bewildered by Madison’s opposition. Hadn’t Madison been in the forefront of those in the 1780s who had fought for a stronger national government? Hadn’t Madison written the Virginia Plan, which was the model for the final Constitution? And hadn’t Madison joined with Hamilton to write The Federalist Papers in support of the Constitution? A mystified Hamilton could conclude only that Madison had succumbed to the views of his Virginia constituents and to pressure from his close friend Thomas Jefferson. This is essentially the explanation that McCraw relies on to account for Madison’s surprising change of mind.

But such an explanation belittles the integrity and the independence of Madison’s mind. He did not oppose Hamilton’s program simply because he was concerned about his Virginia constituents or in thrall to the thinking of his friend Jefferson. He vehemently opposed Hamilton’s program because he rightly believed that Hamilton was trying to create the kind of fiscal-military state that he and other radical Whigs deeply feared. That was not at all the kind of national government that he had worked for in 1787. As a careful reading of his Federalist Number 10 reveals, Madison had expected the new national government to become a kind of adjudicatory body—to become, as he put it in a letter to Washington in 1787, a “disinterested and dispassionate umpire in disputes between different passions and interests” in the several states. In fact, he had thought that the new federal government might play the super-political neutral role that the British crown had ideally been supposed to play in the empire.

So when McCraw says that Hamilton “was certainly no monarchist,” he is technically correct. But the Treasury secretary did admire the English constitution, and he did aim to approximate the English political and financial system as much as possible while keeping within a republican framework—perhaps, as some contemporaries noted, creating an American republican monarchy in the same manner that Augustus covertly created a monarchical empire while claiming to be continuing the Roman Republic.

Nothing like a fiscal-military state developed in America over the next half-century, and so many historians, including McCraw, find it hard to take seriously all of Jefferson’s and Madison’s talk of “monocrats” and “Monarchical federalists.” Some of them have accused Madison of being paranoid; one of them has even claimed that Madison’s view “was, to speak plainly, nuts.” But Jefferson and Madison were sincere in their fears, even though we know now that they were mistaken. They and the other Republicans did not know their future any more than we know ours.

THE REPUBLICANS’ fears more or less disappeared with Jefferson’s election to the presidency in 1800. Jefferson got rid of as much of Hamilton’s and the Federalists’ program as he could. He ended the formality and the pomp of the Federalist presidency, greatly reduced the minuscule army and navy, ended all excise taxes, and cut the government’s tiny bureaucracy to the bone, claiming that the offices under the Federalists had become “too complicated, too expensive” and had “multiplied unnecessarily.” But he was mortified that his government had inherited “the contracted, English, half-lettered ideas of Hamilton.... We can pay off his debt in 15 years, but we can never get rid of his financial system.” He hated all banks and wanted to get rid of the Bank of the United States, too, but his able secretary of the Treasury, Albert Gallatin, who knew about finance, banks, and credit, talked him out of it. Gallatin served as secretary of the Treasury for thirteen years in two different presidential administrations—the longest serving Treasury secretary in American history.

Gallatin was born in the independent republic of Geneva in 1761 and therefore, unlike Hamilton, was a real foreigner. Although he had no prior mercantile experience, he had grown up in the busy city of Geneva, and he was smart, perhaps not as smart as Hamilton but a whole lot wiser. He had graduated from the Academy of Geneva first in his class in mathematics, Latin translation, and “natural philosophy,” that is, science. He came to the United States in 1780 as a young man of nineteen in search of land so that he could become a real gentleman-landowner. But he eventually came to realize that his talents lay not in land and agriculture but in the management of money and other financial instruments. After becoming a citizen in 1785, he entered the legislature of Pennsylvania as a representative of the western part of the state; and he soon began overseeing much of the state’s financial matters.

In 1794, Gallatin was elected to the House of Representatives, where he quickly became a major force in the Republicans’ opposition to the Federalists. “His facility with numbers, his ability to absorb complex financial data, and his zeal in attacking Hamilton’s economic program,” writes McCraw, “made him a priceless asset to the Republican Party.” It was inevitable that he would become Jefferson’s secretary of the Treasury.

Perhaps because he was a real foreigner, Gallatin had an acute appreciation of the difference between America and the Old World. America’s economic development, he said, owed much of its success to “the absence of those systems of internal restrictions and monopoly which continue to disfigure the state of society in other countries.” Although he supported the Bank of the United States and appreciated the sometime need for governmental borrowing, he was a good Republican in his desire to pay off the public debt and in his aversion to big government and to any sort of large military establishment. But more than many other Republicans, he believed strongly in internal improvements and in a diversified economy for the United States; and his “Report on Roads and Canals” in 1808 and “Report on Manufactures” in 1810 were state papers that rivaled those of Hamilton in vision and importance. He was less of a strict constitutionalist than Jefferson, and he helped to convince Jefferson to purchase Louisiana without waiting for a constitutional amendment.

Gallatin was the hardest-working member of the administration and was always loyal to the president, even when he disagreed with him. He strongly opposed Jefferson’s and Madison’s visionary alternative to the use of military force—the embargo of 1807–1808, which withheld all international commerce carried on by Americans. If England’s violation of American neutral rights and its impressing of American sailors were to be stopped, Gallatin told Jefferson, the embargo was not the way to do it. He pointed out that enforcing such an embargo would be difficult and would seriously violate Republican principles. Perhaps owing to his sophisticated understanding of how economies worked, an understanding not shared by Jefferson or Madison, Gallatin realized that momentous actions by governments often had unintended consequences. “Governmental prohibitions,” he told Jefferson on the eve of the passage of the embargo act, “do always more mischief than had been calculated; and it is not without much hesitation that a statesman should hazard to regulate the concerns of individuals as if he could do it better than themselves.” This was wise Republican advice, but Jefferson ignored it.

After fifteen months of the Treasury Department’s strenuous and harsh efforts to enforce the embargo, in blatant violation of the Fourth Amendment and all the drastic economic consequences that Gallatin had predicted, the embargo was repealed. War, which Gallatin had preferred to a permanent embargo, became inevitable. During the War of 1812 Gallatin managed the finances of the government as well as he could in the absence of the Bank of the United States. Despite his efforts on behalf of the Bank in 1811, the Republican Congress had foolishly refused to re-charter it.

Although Gallatin had preferred war to the embargo, he came to realize that the war was a huge mistake. When the possibility of a negotiated peace opened up, he volunteered to be one of the negotiators. He became the leader of the motley American delegation in Ghent and was crucial in keeping it together. No one was more responsible than he for the peace treaty with Great Britain signed on Christmas Eve 1814.

As McCraw points out, Gallatin went on to live a long and useful life. He became minister to France and later to Great Britain, and engaged also in several other diplomatic missions. In 1828 he moved to New York City, became president of the newly chartered National Bank of New York, and helped to found what became New York University. In his later years he became an expert on Native American ethnology and published two books on the subject. He was unsuccessful in persuading President Andrew Jackson to re-charter the Second Bank of the United States and unsuccessful in preventing America’s war with Mexico. He died in 1849 at age eighty-eight, having lived, as McCraw correctly concludes, “one of the longest, most honorable, and most productive public lives of any member of his generation.” One of McCraw’s accomplishments in his book is highlighting the significance of this much neglected figure.

IN THE THIRD PART of his book, titled “The Legacies,” McCraw has four brief chapters on several desultory subjects: “Immigrant Exceptionalism?”; “Comparisons and Contingencies”; “Capitalism and Credit”; and “The Political Economy of Hamilton and Gallatin.” In the first of those chapters, he revisits his argument that immigrants were especially knowledgeable about finance and business, citing the additional examples of William Duer, Stephen Girard, John Jacob Astor, and several others to bolster his case. But his chapter on “Comparisons and Contingencies” is truly remarkable and strange.

In it McCraw suddenly shifts gears and suggests that what he has been doing throughout the previous nine-tenths of his book may not be right after all. Too many historical works “that focus on the founders,” he now admits, “tend to downplay the fluid, fast-changing circumstances in which events compelled them to act.” Readers of these histories “encounter versions of history in which mature, fully formed statesmen acted according to coherent, well-developed doctrines that came to bear their names.” This comes, he says, from “looking only backward—rather than also forward, from the perspectives of the participants.” From the participants’ point of view, one sees only uncertain contingencies and protean situations where the participants have to make up new answers as they go along. “Much of history is a story of events that might have turned out differently.” If the Articles of Confederation had been reformed we might not have had the new Constitution of 1787. “Events, or the consequences of previous events, shaped public policy, which in turn shaped subsequent events and policies.”

McCraw then proceeds to a brief three-page summary of events that he has already fully described in his book, only now he emphasizes how contingent everything was and how every event from the ratification of the Jay Treaty to Jefferson’s election could have turned out differently. How lucky we were, he says. Think what would have happened if Hamilton’s program had not been enacted. “The quick prosperity that followed Hamilton’s program almost surely would not have occurred, and the depression of the 1780s might have continued.”

Actually, that may not be true: entrepreneurial forces unleashed by the Revolution and already visible in the 1780s may have been strong enough to survive and prosper even under a reformed Articles of Confederation. After all, the kind of federal government that Jefferson created after 1800 intentionally resembled the Confederation. Without the Bank of the United States, the states would still have had chartered banks. It is too bad that McCraw did not begin his book with this fascinating chapter and make its point the central theme of his book. It would have made for a much more original and accurate book.

I say more accurate because, as McCraw suggests, most of the Founders were caught up in circumstances they scarcely comprehended, and they had little sense of where the future was taking them. Fast-moving developments overwhelmed nearly all their high-minded intentions. Hamilton especially misread the future and was never in control of events. He never really understood the way the American economy was developing. He and the other Federalists tended to favor big merchants and financiers and to ignore artisans, small businessmen, and farmers. He expected the Bank of the United States to create several branches that would eventually absorb the state banks and give the Bank a monopoly over the nation’s banking. Moreover, his Bank of the United States was intended to make credit available only to large merchants engaged in overseas commerce and others who wanted short-term loans of ninety days or less. At the outset most banks, including the Bank of the United States, did not want to get involved as yet with long-term mortgage loans to farmers—to do so would tie up money for too long a time.

But that kind of restricted credit could not be maintained in a society that contained the largest proportion of voters in the world, nearly all eager to pursue happiness by making money. In spite of opposition from Hamilton and the Bank, ordinary farmers and entrepreneurs who wanted long-term credit pressured their state legislatures to create that long-term credit. The Constitution had in fact forbidden the states from issuing paper money, but the states got around this extremely limiting prohibition by creating dozens upon dozens of banks that issued the money that the entrepreneurial-minded population wanted, especially in the North. Every town seemed to want a bank. By 1818, Kentucky had forty-three new banks, two of them in towns that had fewer than one hundred inhabitants. The proliferation of paper money was not at all what Hamilton and the Federalists expected, and they were appalled by it, even though all the paper supplied the wherewithal that made possible the phenomenal growth of the American economy.

IN OTHER WAYS, too, Hamilton and his fellow Federalists revealed their insensitivity to the entrepreneurial needs of ordinary farmers, artisans, and small businessmen. Despite Hamilton’s interest in economic diversity and manufacturing, he ignored the interests of the artisans and the manufacturers. Hamilton’s tariffs were not protective; they were revenue-raising. Indeed, he did not like protective tariffs, preferring giving bounties to the manufacturers instead. Those bounties tended to benefit manufacturers who exported articles rather than those who manufactured goods for domestic consumption. In fact, Hamilton and the Federalists preferred to think of commerce almost exclusively in the traditional terms of overseas trade. Consequently, they ignored the significance of the developing domestic market, which soon came to dominate American business in the burgeoning Northern states. It is thus not surprising that the artisan-manufacturers and other businessmen, who had been strong supporters of the Federalists in 1787–1788, now began going over to the Republicans in ever increasing numbers.

Gallatin had a somewhat better understanding of what was happening. Although he supported the re-chartering of the Bank of the United States, he did not like—any better than the Federalists did—all the wildcat state banks and their emissions of proliferating paper money that was often insufficiently backed up by gold and silver. In fact, one of the reasons he so badly wanted the Bank to be re-chartered in 1811 was its ability to curb the state banks’ excessive issues of paper.

Unlike Hamilton and the Federalists, Gallatin at least grasped the increasing importance of the domestic marketplace and the peculiar nature of America’s economic system. In a notable speech in the House of Representatives in 1799, not mentioned by McCraw, he set forth the way in which America differed commercially and socially from the former mother country. In Britain, he told the Congress, the different trades and occupations were “so well distinguished that a merchant and a farmer are rarely combined in the same person; a merchant is a merchant, and nothing but a merchant; a manufacturer is only a manufacturer; a farmer is merely a farmer; but this is not the case in this country.” In America, “the different professions and traders are blended together in the same person; the same man being frequently a farmer and a merchant and perhaps a manufacturer.” The consequence, said Gallatin, was that the United States was no longer the exclusively agricultural nation that Jefferson idealized. Nearly everyone was a farmer and something else besides. “Go into the interior of the country,” he said, “and you will scarcely find a farmer who is not, in some degree, a trader. In a grazing part of the country, you will find them buying and selling cattle; in other parts you will find them distillers, tanners, or brick-makers. So that from one end of the United States to the other, the people are generally traders.”

For this reason, emphasizing “the agrarian nature” of the society as McCraw does—a society in which nineteen out of twenty Americans were farmers and in which “the principal economic interest among most segments of society was land”—is very misleading, since large numbers of that society, in the North especially, were becoming some of the most commercially involved people in the Western world, producing, selling, and buying among themselves to an extent that no one in 1789 had ever anticipated. And the economy that resulted was anything but orderly. In fact, it could not have been more wild and risky. Many businesses failed, but enough succeeded to allow the whole economy to grow. All this commercial chaos led many Americans increasingly to believe that America’s marketplace was uncontrollable and beyond the ability of anyone to manage. It had to be instead in the hands of providence, which many Americans soon came to identify with progress.

In his two final chapters, McCraw seems to take back much of what he said previously. He reverts to emphasizing the importance of statesmen such as Hamilton and Gallatin in managing financial affairs. Capitalism, he contends, is not “the natural state of human affairs,” and “from its earliest years down to the present, a capitalist system has been uncommonly difficult to organize and maintain.” Since Americans in the early Republic were deeply suspicious of credit, despite the fact that it “stands at the heart of all capitalist systems,” both Hamilton and Gallatin realized that America’s system of credit “had to be managed with extreme care.” Although both statesmen understood that “successful capitalism requires the active promotion of entrepreneurship,” they also knew that capitalism needs “constant monitoring by government to ensure that the system does not spin out of control.”

HERE MCCRAW seems to be offering a very obvious message for our own time. In their promotion of credit and banking, the two statesmen “were defining one of the key elements in what came to be called capitalism—the system that would propel the phenomenal growth of the American economy.” But how responsible were these leaders for that growth? With all the bank bills flying about in the early decades of the nineteenth century, the nation’s system of credit was scarcely being managed by anyone. Its system of public credit had certainly spun out of control. By 1842, eight states and the Territory of Florida were bankrupt, and three others (out of a total of twenty-six states) were in very serious financial shape.

This seems to suggest that the phenomenal growth of the economy in the early decades of the nineteenth century came largely from below, from ordinary people borrowing money and producing and trading things, not mainly from above, and not from the decisions of political leaders. McCraw’s brief intermezzo message near the end of his book in which he stresses contingency, uncontrollable circumstances, and an unknown and unexpected future seems ultimately to be what captures the reader’s mind. We may not know what we are doing with our own public finances, but perhaps we may take some comfort in the fact that the Founders, two centuries ago, did not know what they were doing, either.


Gordon S. Wood is the Alva O. Way University professor emeritus at Brown University and is the author, most recently, of
The Idea of America: Reflections on the Birth of the United States. This article appeared in the December 20, 2012 issue of the magazine under the headline “The Birth of American Finance.”